History does not crawl. History jumps.
Nassim Nicholas Taleb (2008).
In these dark times of ’Coronacoma’ for the World Economy, the European Monetary Union is on the brink… Again. This time, it could be truly different. Countries opposed to any kind of debt mutualization properly ordered hinder de facto the achievement of a federal leap that it is desperately needed to complete the monetary union. Without this giant leap, there are real risks of implosion for the eurozone and, even, the whole EU. This brief note tries to explain why the US historical experience could be inspiring for Europeans in a situation where the concept of radical uncertainty is especially relevant.
1. White Swans and Black Swans
As noted by the French Philosopher Edgar Morin, we live a period full of uncertainties. We simply do not know enough about the origin of the virus, its potential mutations, the population more susceptible to be infected, its overall harmfulness… We simply do not know enough. Contrary to what most people think in normal times (non-crises times), life itself is full of uncertainties. The main message of Morin is that we need to expect the unforeseeable. This simple and powerful philosophical view has huge implications on the way we build theoretical and empirical models to forecast economic and financial outcomes.
To fully grasp the potential implications of Morin’s view, we must clarify how we define the concept of uncertainty. To do this, we can start from the definition of Nassim Taleb given to the well-known Black Swan (Times, 2010). A Black Swan is ‘an unexpected event of large magnitude and consequence that could have been foreseen.’ In this respect, a White Swan is ‘an expected event of large magnitude and consequence (consequently it has been foreseen).’ Many observers, as Roubini (2020), think that the current global pandemic is a White Swan not a Black one, in reason of the many warnings issued by epidemiologists about the possibility of acute pandemic episodes following the epidemic episodes of the SARS crisis in 2002-2003 and the Middle East respiratory syndrome (MERS) crisis that started in 2012.
However, there is a third kind of uncertainty that relates to the concept of Radical Uncertainty introduced by Frank Knight and championed by John Maynard Keynes. This concept is close to the ‘State Space Uncertainty’ introduced by Bradley and Drechsler (2014). This type of uncertainty can be defined as follows: ‘state space uncertainty arises when an agent is aware of the possibility that she has entirely omitted a state of the world from the state space.’ In this case, the addition of a catch-all state of the world does not reduce the uncertainty since the agents do not know which events are included in the N + 1 state of the world and, thus, they cannot attribute probabilities to these events. To conclude on this part, this type of uncertainty is irreducible. We simply do not know as noted by Keynes. An event characterized by Radical Uncertainty is an unexpected event of large magnitude and consequence that could not have been foreseen.
2. Lessons from History
As discussed in the previous section, the current period is characterized by several sources of uncertainties. Even if it is difficult to claim with certainty which concept of uncertainty is particularly relevant to analyze the near future, it is quite clear that economic and financial forecasts are deeply affected by these uncertainties. Indeed, many of the economic and financial forecasts made at the beginning of this year about, inter alia, the world economic growth are obsolete and irrelevant now. From a conceptual perspective, it is far from impossible that the current forecasts will face the same fate. Consequently, as the future is uncertain, it could be helpful to look at historical experiences.
Ryan and Loughlin (2018) analyze the historical experiences of three monetary unions namely the Latin Monetary Union, the Scandinavian Monetary Union and the Austro-Hungarian Monetary Union. In an attempt to derive some lessons for the European Monetary Union, they conclude that these Monetary Unions did not survive to World War I mainly for two reasons, firstly, the national rivalries, secondly, the non-existence of robust institutions such as a common central bank and unified fiscal policy. Besides, in addition to the two aforementioned conclusions, they highlight three other points in their comparison with the contemporary European Monetary Union, namely the fragility of Monetary Unions through History, the importance of economic convergence to root the formal arrangements into economic and financial reality, and the importance of institutions to curb moral hazard.
After the end of the euro crisis in late 2012, some observers try to enlighten the European experience thanks to a comparison with the American monetary history. For example, Gaspar (2015) proposes to explore the early U.S. historical experience to glean some lessons for Europeans. He explores the decisive role of Alexander Hamilton, the first U.S. Treasury Secretary from 1789 to 1795. When he started, the Federal Government was in default. After he left, the U.S. Treasuries became the ultimate safe asset. Furthermore, he emphasizes that this Hamiltonian moment illustrates very well the conjunction of three intertwined fields: politics, fiscal policy and financial activities.
Furthermore, he tries to glean some lessons for the Europeans from the Hamiltonian moment and underlines that these three aforementioned fields (i.e. politics, fiscal policy and financial activities) are intertwined in a complex manner and that they constitute an array of systemic problems that requires systemic solutions.
Certainly, politics is very important. In this field, Gaspar underlines three fundamental points. The first fundamental political point is related to distributional issues between Member States (about the question of legacy assets), but also within Member States (between generations). Then, the second fundamental political point is about public finances, in Europe, they have a special place since they are at the heart of the social contract. The Welfare State appears to be in stark contrast with the minimalist conception of Hamilton. In the 18th century U.S., most of the debt has been accumulated to finance the War of Independence, so for ‘federal reasons.’ It is not the case, for Europeans of the 20th and 21st centuries where indebtedness has grown for ‘national reasons’, to finance the Welfare States after the 1970s energy crises. Finally, the third fundamental political point concerns the true nature of the political system itself. Indeed, the European Union is based on an inter-state (inter-national) political system. This original institutional construction has its roots in the tragedy of World War II.
Besides, the sustainability of public finances is essential. Indeed, we can consider along with Gaspar that members of a fully-fledged federation have to adopt rules in order to avoid bankruptcy (it was the case in more than half of American States after a series of defaults between 1841 and 1842). In the same time, a member of a federation cannot issue its own debt in the name of this federation. Thus, the importance of a no bail-out clause is essential to ensure the viability of the federation. As noted by Gaspar, in the U.S., this required the Constitution to replace the Articles of the Confederation, not a small change. Besides, an economic and political union requires necessarily the means of financing of its public expenditures. Simply put, it means that if indebtedness and, consequently expenditures are pooled at the federal level, then the federation needs taxation powers. Otherwise, the sustainability of public finances rests on the shoulders of Member States (like in the European Monetary Union) and is subject to national rivalries that can undermine deeply its financial stability.
These two last points, (i) politics and (ii) sustainability of public finances are enough to underline the huge differences between the Alexander Hamilton’s epoch and the current crisis. Even if it is true that the French President, Emmanuel Macron has claimed that ‘Nous sommes en guerre’ (Le Monde, 2020), we can wonder if the current pandemic will lead the Europeans towards a (common) greater good, as the War of Independence did for the Thirteen Colonies. Here, it is important to quote the words of the late Paul Volcker in 2012 after the euro crisis: ‘As I see it, Europe is at an Alexander Hamilton moment, but there’s no Alexander Hamilton in sight’ (Kluth, 2020).
3. Eurobonds versus Hamilton Bonds
After the euro crisis in late 2012, the opposition to any kind of debt mutualization was quite widespread amongst politicians and in economic circles. Some (few) voices have claimed that the European Monetary Union could not survive another crisis without a giant leap in terms of political and economic integration. Some countries were opposed to any kind of debt mutualization mainly due to a rationale based on the concept of moral hazard. Indeed, without a complete political integration, many observers firmly believed that non-virtuous countries could be tempted to conduct unsustainable budgetary policies, consequently the financial health of the whole monetary union could be in danger.
This rationale may contain some kernels of truth, but it misses the point since we can reasonably consider that southern peripheral countries have played the role of consumers of last resort (Geerolf and Grjebine, 2020). Indeed, these two rationales namely the first one, non-virtuous southern peripheral countries unprepared for crises and the second one, southern peripheral countries as consumers of last resort are clearly incompatible from a political perspective as shown by the tensions between Wopke Hoestra, the Dutch finance minister, and António Costa, the Prime Minister of Portugal at the end of March.
During this very peculiar crisis, the opposition to any kind of debt mutualization seems to be more and more feeble. Several observers like Davras (2020) underline that the recent measures taken by the European governance may not suffice to avoid market pressures on sovereign debts in the near future and that a partial debt mutualization will be necessary. Reichlin (2020) goes further by arguing that the current crisis could be an opportunity to enhance fiscal coordination to face catastrophic events. Those changes in the economic consensus and in the political realm are more than welcome, but as always the devil is in the details (Tanzi, 2020).
While it is clear that countries opposed to any kind of debt mutualization hinder de facto a federal leap that is desperately needed to complete the monetary union, it is less clear that all kinds of debt mutualization will necessarily enhance the resilience of the monetary union to violent exogenous shocks. Indeed, two conditions seem to be necessary (but probably non-sufficient) to achieve an orderly debt mutualization. Firstly, some (many) fiscal powers have to be transferred at the level of the monetary union. Secondly, mechanisms that preclude unsustainable fiscal policies (i.e. a no bail-out clause) have to be designed. Without these two conditions that have to be decided by national democratic institutions, a disorderly debt mutualization could have the same effect as no mutualization at all (i.e. risks of economic and political disintegration for the union).
Without these aforementioned conditions these proposals for debt mutualization in the European monetary union follow the same logic, not the one of Hamilton. Indeed, the debt will be issued by each Member State individually but guaranteed by all countries in the euro area. Kluth (2020) draws an interesting analogy. The Eurobonds proposals are equivalent to a situation where California is selling debt and all the other states guarantee it. We can clearly see that Texas, for example, will have no interest to participate in such a scheme. Besides, the Californians’ reaction could be very dire when Texans will show up in Sacramento to profess budget cuts. Replace Texas by Germany and California by Italy and you will see why we need Hamilton Bonds not Eurobonds.
Nota bene: This article is also available on the ERMEES website.
References
- Richard Bradley, Mareile Drechsler. Types of Uncertainty. Erkenntnis 79, 1225-1248 (2014). Retrieved from URL.
- Zsolt Davras. The fiscal consequences of the pandemic. Bruegel. Accessed 22 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Vitor Gaspar. The Making of a Continental Financial System: Lessons for Europe from Early American History, Journal of European Integration, 37:7, 847-859 (2015). Retrieved from URL.
- François Geerolf, Thomas Grjebine. Coronavirus : “L’Europe doit cesser son jeu de dupes”. CEPII le Blog. Accessed 22 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Andreas Kluth. Corona Bonds Could Save the Euro or Sink It. Bloomberg. Accessed 21 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Paul Krugman. Notes on the Coronacoma (Wonkish). The New York Times. Accessed 13 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Le Monde. ‘ Nous sommes en guerre’: le verbatim du discours d’Emmanuel Macron. Accessed 21 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Edgar Morin. Nous devons vivre avec l’incertitude. CNRS Le journal. Accessed 6 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Lucrezia Reichlin. COVID-19 Is an Opportunity for Europe. Project Syndicate. Accessed 22 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Nouriel Roubini. The White Swans of 2020. Project Syndicate. Accessed 18 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- John Ryan, John Loughlin. Lessons from historical monetary unions – is the European monetary union making the same mistakes? International Economics and Economic Policy 15, 709–725 (2018). Retrieved from URL.
- Vito Tanzi. Letter: Eurobond: a good idea but the devil is in the detail. The Financial Times. Accessed 24 April 2020. Retrieved from URL.
- Times. (2010, December 3). 10 Questions for Nassim Taleb [Video]. YouTube. Retrieved from URL.